The Black Scholes Model and Implied Volatility


The Black Scholes model (BS model) is a mathematical model for pricing an option, either a call option or a put option. The standard BS model is only used to price European options, because it does not take into account that an option might be exercised before the maturity date. The BS model is very important to understand, because it is one of the key concepts used for option pricing.

Key Assumptions of the Black Scholes Model

In the previous lecture, we focussed on the derivation process behind the BS model. The derived BS model assumes that the financial instruments have lognormal distributed prices. The BS model has been constructed by using this- and other key assumptions. Other key assumptions are:

  • The underlying asset has no dividend payments.
  • There is a constant risk-free rate.
  • The asset is traded continuously over time.
  • The asset is traded in a perfect market, in which there are no taxes and no transactions costs.
  • Another very important assumption is that the BS model uses a constant volatility, which is a very important assumption and important to understand.

No Dividend Payments

This assumption states that the underlying asset, such as a stock, does not pay dividends. This is important because dividends would reduce the stock’s price on the ex-dividend date, introducing an additional variable to model. By ignoring dividends, the model simplifies the asset’s price evolution.

Constant Risk-Free Rate

The BS model assumes a constant risk-free rate, often represented by Quicklatex. Com 943125815804c896c38527bb8882e3cd l3, which is used to discount the option’s future payoffs. In reality, risk-free rates can vary over time, but assuming a constant rate simplifies calculations and allows for closed-form solutions.

Continuous Trading

The assumption that the asset is traded continuously over time allows the model to use stochastic calculus to derive the Black-Scholes equation. In the real world, trading is not continuous (e.g., markets close overnight), which can lead to gaps in pricing that the model doesn’t account for.

Perfect Market

In a perfect market, there are no transaction costs or taxes, and buying/selling does not influence the asset’s price. This is clearly an idealization; in practice, transaction costs and taxes can significantly impact profitability and thus option pricing.

Constant Volatility

This assumption posits that the asset’s volatility, often denoted by Quicklatex. Com 6b4bc7aff63e3fde7fd212232efe9866 l3, remains constant over the life of the option. Volatility is a measure of how much the asset price is expected to fluctuate. In reality, volatility can be time-varying and even “jumpy,” but assuming constant volatility allows for a closed-form solution to the Black-Scholes equation.

Each of these assumptions plays a role in simplifying the complexities of financial markets to a level where a closed-form solution like the Black-Scholes equation is possible. However, keep in mind that the simplifications also limit the model’s accuracy.

Pricing of European Call- and Put Options

The pricing of European calls and puts is as follows. The pricing of a European call option on a non-dividend paying stock is given in Equation 1.

(1)   Quicklatex. Com c5ac58ebc89561a4d4ec8393e4ebd1cd l3

The pricing of a European put option on a non-dividend paying stock is given in Equation 2.

(2)   Quicklatex. Com a63cbb2c71dd8c0e28e442105849dee2 l3

In both Equation 1 and Equation 2:

  • Quicklatex. Com bd057a5c339c950429dcfc0765551ec5 l3 is the distribution function of the standardized normal distribution.
  • Quicklatex. Com 01331611baedb77e283e8edf10472508 l3
  • Quicklatex. Com 6fa16f241020cefaa9b9b46c344042da l3

These equations form the Black Scholes model, also known as the Black Scholes Merton model. Let’s get into examples for both a call option and a put option.

Example: Consider a European call that matures at Quicklatex. Com ec26f656893f11a2e7a5791f9a46d614 l3. The exercise price is Quicklatex. Com db0d3ab7db18e030932c065a16a4266c l3, the current stock price is Quicklatex. Com 8e7daa03261ebba59aac5f90b637675e l3, the volatility is Quicklatex. Com b91b7d7ac4faf0c3127be90476cf979b l3 and the risk-free rate is 5%. 

Step 1: Compute Quicklatex. Com 09d70b66513deeda0838cc2d61746b25 l3 and Quicklatex. Com d4fcaa62d43f25a252b1bcab04f30202 l3.

(3)   Quicklatex. Com 92b949b282429b69f42e38d4fc1b0515 l3

(4)   Quicklatex. Com 07f9edce22debb34b43857ad7c3f314c l3

Step 2: Determine Quicklatex. Com bd5b0595057a9cbbcbac0269ee92fb2f l3 and Quicklatex. Com abfd2dba6ab1c465f8aeb3223c98ba5e l3. To do this, check a table for the z-statistic for the normal distribution.

(5)   Quicklatex. Com 96de0170d76987566c3e1227b1b7c1a8 l3

(6)   Quicklatex. Com 1fb1ca2ddde7c73f64ea5b62637bb1d9 l3

Step 3: Compute the value of the call option at Quicklatex. Com d0b55db58256fbf21ed94fa50c05c45c l3.

(7)   Quicklatex. Com 18688c7f218d36ec46dca1d96e7a45f6 l3

(8)   Quicklatex. Com 6b07bce26d036e02348424770585c4d1 l3

Example: Consider a European put that matures at Quicklatex. Com ec26f656893f11a2e7a5791f9a46d614 l3. The exercise price is Quicklatex. Com db0d3ab7db18e030932c065a16a4266c l3, the current stock price is Quicklatex. Com 8e7daa03261ebba59aac5f90b637675e l3, , the volatility is Quicklatex. Com b91b7d7ac4faf0c3127be90476cf979b l3 and the risk-free rate is 5%. 

Step 1: Compute Quicklatex. Com 09d70b66513deeda0838cc2d61746b25 l3 and Quicklatex. Com d4fcaa62d43f25a252b1bcab04f30202 l3.

(9)   Quicklatex. Com 92b949b282429b69f42e38d4fc1b0515 l3

(10)   Quicklatex. Com 07f9edce22debb34b43857ad7c3f314c l3

Step 2: Determine Quicklatex. Com bd5b0595057a9cbbcbac0269ee92fb2f l3 and Quicklatex. Com abfd2dba6ab1c465f8aeb3223c98ba5e l3. To do this, check a table for the z-statistic for the normal distribution.

(11)   Quicklatex. Com 7a5b4e1b6e1b5dfa1871dfe9a569b695 l3

(12)   Quicklatex. Com e16cf2e5db272c1b7b118a375168f27d l3

Step 3: Compute the value of the put option at Quicklatex. Com d0b55db58256fbf21ed94fa50c05c45c l3.

(13)   Quicklatex. Com 72b5f524441a846af61f139a06cb8913 l3

(14)   Quicklatex. Com e0f36c8367113c63be5fbbe5ea1860da l3

As we can see in the formula, the volatility is an important input in the BS model. The higher the volatility is, the more expensive a call- or put option becomes. A higher volatility means that there is a larger probability that there will be a large price movement, which is a risk for the seller of the option contract. The BS model uses a fixed volatility. This volatility is called the implied volatility, which is the volatility that must be used in the BS model to obtain the option price that is observed in the market. In other words:

(15)   Quicklatex. Com 63f69338bd1b5e2ad23b6ca315ca2d29 l3

Implied Volatility Smile and Smirk

Empirical evidence shows us that, even though the BS model is very popular, the assumptions for a constant volatility does not hold. Empirical evidence shows us that the implied volatility depends on – for example – the time to maturity and on the exercise price. A short-dated option contract often results in a low implied volatility. On the other hand, a long-dated option contract often results in a high implied volatility. If we would plot the implied volatility against the exercise price, the BS model would suggest that the plot would be flat, since it should have a constant volatility. However, in reality we have a so-called volatility smile or volatility skew. 

First, let’s elaborate on the volatility smile. A volatility smile is a graph shape in which the implied volatility is plotted against the strike price. Because of its shape it is called the volatility smile. Volatility smiles can be seen when various options with the same underlying asset and the same expiration date are compared for different strike prices. The smile pattern is commonly seen when equity options and options in the forex market are close to expiration. Other patterns occur in other circumstances, which will be elaborated on later on this section. In Figure 1, the implied volatility rises when the underlying asset of an option is further out of the money (OTM, a term to describe an option contract that will not directly give the buyer the right to buy the underlying asset below its current value or sell it above its current value) or in the money (ITM, a term used to describe an option contract that gives the buyer the right to buy the underlying asset below its current value or sell it above its current value), compared to at the money (ATM, when the option’s strike price is identical to the price of the underlying asset). 

Implied volatility smile - black scholes model
Figure 1 – Implied volatility ‘smile’.

Demand drives the prices, which affect the implied volatility. ATM options are the most liquid contracts on the market. Therefore, their price is less volatile than the ones that are more ITM or OTM. The ITM- and OTM options are more driven by fear than greed. “People don’t pay much for flood insurance in the desert. But people pay considerable sums for flood insurance in coastal areas, specifically during hurricane season”. The psychology related to fear leads us more towards the skewed volatility graph in Figure 2, in which the graph shows more of a ‘smirk’ instead of a ‘smile’. 

Implied volatility smirk - black scholes model
Figure 2 – Implied volatility ‘smirk’ – reversed skew.

Near-expiration options might align more with the volatility smile, but long-term equity options and index options tend to align more with the volatility smirk. Just as with the volatility smile, the volatility smirk shows the difference in implied volatility between OTM-, ITM- and ATM options. The sentiment and the supply and demand schedules for the options with different strike prices affect the implied volatility. The smirk in Figure 2 is also called a reversed skew. The reverse skew pattern suggests that ITM calls and OTM puts are more expensive compared to OTM calls and ITM puts.

The reversed skew pattern is often explained in different ways. Here is a list of explanations:

  • Leverage effect
    One explanation for the volatility smirk can be attributed to the leverage effect, which is the inverse relationship between the price of an asset and its volatility. When an asset’s price declines, its volatility tends to increase. This is because as prices fall, the leverage of a company’s debt increases, making it riskier, and driving up the volatility. This effect causes the implied volatility of OTM put options to be higher than that of OTM call options, resulting in the volatility smirk.
  • Market crashes and investor sentiment
    Another contributing factor is the tendency for markets to experience larger declines during crashes than gains during rallies. Investors’ fear and risk aversion in times of market stress leads to a higher demand for downside protection through the purchase of OTM put options. This increased demand drives up the implied volatility for these options, again creating the volatility smirk.
  • Market inefficiencies
    Some researchers have argued that the volatility smirk may be a result of market inefficiencies, where traders do not price options correctly based on the historical distribution of asset returns. If traders systematically underestimate the likelihood of extreme negative events, the resulting market prices of options could exhibit a volatility smirk pattern.
  • Jump risk and fat-tailed distribution
    The distribution of stock returns is often assumed to follow a normal distribution in many options pricing models. However, empirical evidence suggests that stock returns exhibit fat tails and are prone to extreme events or jumps. The Black-Scholes model makes several simplifying assumptions, one of which is that stock returns follow a log-normal distribution. This means that the continuously compounded returns (the natural logarithm of the ratio of the ending price to the starting price) are normally distributed. Under this assumption, stock price movements are assumed to be continuous, with no sudden jumps, and are characterised by a symmetric, bell-shaped curve. When option prices are corrected to account for the increased probability of extreme negative events, the resulting implied volatilities exhibit a volatility smirk pattern.

    In reality, however, empirical research has shown that the distribution of stock returns deviates from the normal distribution. Some key deviations include:
    • Fat tails: The distribution of stock returns exhibits heavier tails compared to the normal distribution. This means that extreme events, both positive and negative, occur more frequently than what the normal distribution would predict. These fat tails can be attributed to events such as financial crises, natural disasters, or other occurrences that cause large price swings.
    • Skewness: Stock returns are often found to be negatively skewed, meaning that the distribution is asymmetric with a longer tail on the negative side. This implies that large negative returns are more common than large positive returns. The normal distribution, on the other hand, is symmetric and does not account for this skewness.
    • Kurtosis: The distribution of stock returns tends to have a higher kurtosis than the normal distribution, which means it has more probability mass in the tails and less in the center. In other words, extreme events are more likely, and moderate fluctuations are less likely compared to a normal distribution.
    • Jump risk: The Black-Scholes model assumes that stock price movements are continuous and do not exhibit sudden jumps. However, real-world stock returns often involve discontinuous jumps due to unexpected news, political events, or other factors that cause abrupt changes in stock prices.
  • Another reason is that ITM calls have become very popular, which drives up the price of the ITM call options. These call options often offer leveraged contracts, which increases the ROI (Return on Investment).

Another variant of the volatility smirk is the forward skew, shown in Figure 3. In the forward skew pattern, the implied volatility at lower strike prices are lower than the implied volatility at higher strikes. This suggests that OTM calls and ITM puts are in greater demand compared to ITM calls and OTM puts. 

Implied volatility smirk - black scholes model
Figure 3 – Implied volatility ‘smirk’ – forwards skew.

The forward skew, or volatility smirk, is a phenomenon observed in the commodities options market where the implied volatility of options increases as the strike price increases. In other words, out-of-the-money (OTM) call options tend to have higher implied volatilities compared to their out-of-the-money (OTM) put counterparts. This is contrary to the typical assumption that volatility should be constant across all strike prices.

The reasons for the forward skew in the commodities options market are different from those in the equity and index options market. Here are some key factors that contribute to the forward skew in the commodities options market:

  • Supply shocks and price jumps
    The prices of commodities are often influenced by supply shocks resulting from factors such as natural disasters, geopolitical events, or production disruptions. These events can cause sudden and substantial increases in the prices of commodities. As a result, the likelihood of large positive price jumps is higher than that of large negative price jumps. This asymmetric price behavior leads to a forward skew, with OTM call options having higher implied volatilities than OTM put options. When the supply is tight, businesses would rather pay more in order to secure supply. Otherwise they could risk a supply disruption. Think about an agricultural example. In case a long period of frost is incoming, businesses could hedge for a disruption in their crops supply by securing themselves with crops. This drives up the price of the options for the commodities.
  • Storage costs and convenience yield
    Another factor contributing to the forward skew is the presence of storage costs and the convenience yield. Storage costs are the expenses associated with holding and maintaining a physical commodity, while the convenience yield represents the benefits of holding the commodity, such as the ability to meet unexpected demand or take advantage of temporary price spikes. When the convenience yield is greater than the storage costs, the forward curve of the commodity is in backwardation, and the option prices reflect a higher probability of upward price movements, resulting in a forward skew.
  • Market participants and hedging demand
    The structure of the commodities options market is such that producers of commodities often use options to hedge their price risk. They typically buy put options to protect against falling prices, while consumers of commodities buy call options to protect against rising prices. The net effect of this hedging activity is that the demand for call options is often greater than the demand for put options, driving up the implied volatility of call options and creating the forward skew.

Coding the Black Scholes model

Check out the Programming course for a coded class in Python.